|
4#

楼主 |
发表于 2009-6-16 09:13:42
|
只看该作者
Bank-State Cooperation
Since the beginning of bank reform, a separation of government and commercial banking has widened and then narrowed again. Reform's original intent was to separate enterprises from the state and break local government control over lending decisions. But banks discovered that government interference can be a two-edged sword. As banks shook off interference, they also lost implicit government guarantees.
Policy banks felt a deeper impact. Their large loans over long terms make their risks difficult to estimate. Within existing risk management capabilities, they needed a model for collateral while continuing to supply the market with huge sums of money. Without this effort, business expansion would be exceedingly difficult.
Against this backdrop, bank-state cooperation has been revived. In essence, banks decided to seek government credit with explicit or implicit guarantees for their loans.
Ironically, a major measure of success or failure for bank reform was whether banks saw profitability as the ultimate goal. To increase profits, firms should naturally integrate the most efficient market segments. Everyone knows the private sector is more efficient than the public sector. So why would banks choose to shun cooperation with the private sector and cozy up to the state?
First, the government monopolizes the most important resource in the economy: guaranteed government credit. From a revenue perspective, future cash flow of local governments would be insufficient to repay loans. But if we look at market prices for resources under their control – land, monopoly licenses, etc. – local governments are still the largest net asset holders. Not only can they provide implicit guarantees for bank loans, but they can provide explicit ones as well.
Second, after suffering through a loss of control over the non-performing bank loans, regulators adopted a zero tolerance attitude toward loan risk. They also introduced regulations that placed too much emphasis on loan securitization and collateral requirements. Commercial banks even introduced a lifelong lending responsibility system, which shifted focus to the gains and losses of individual loans at the expense of emphasizing overall credit returns.
Third, attempts to limit moral hazard among commercial banks pushed bank lending to the other extreme. It became impossible to effectively prevent borrowers and lenders from conspiring to cheat the system. Lenders naturally became the most obvious suspects in these cases, and private sector borrowing became known as the most likely place for such conspiracies. Working with government departments or state-owned enterprises (SOEs) made it possible to avoid risk. In the end, lenders were only willing to lend to the state and SOEs.
Fourth, the public nature of infrastructure and the stated goal of increasing domestic demand to ensure growth have added legitimacy to bank-state cooperation efforts. Before reforms, propping up troubled SOEs was the main reason for government interference in the loan business. Today, the goal is infrastructure build-out. And that's offered legitimacy to rampant fund-raising among local governments. Proponents of the credit binge note that in economic down times, when market credit is inadequate and deflationary pressure looms, it is the government's duty to provide necessary credit to drive domestic demand. |
|