|
2#

楼主 |
发表于 2008-9-13 12:10:26
|
只看该作者
Bridging these divergent views is tricky because many of the hawks do not just differ in their outlooks, but in how monetary policy works. The conventional view, shared by Mr Bernanke, Donald Kohn, his influential vice-chairman, and their professional staff, is that monetary policy affects inflation via its impact on the real economy. Higher interest rates reduce demand relative to the economy’s potential to supply goods and services. Reduce it enough, and unused slack will accumulate, forcing firms and workers to compete for scarce customers and jobs by lowering prices and wages. The opposite happens when demand rises relative to supply. This relationship is captured in the Phillips curve, which shows inflation falling when unemployment is above its natural rate. In this view, it does not matter whether it is monetary policy or a credit crunch that raises unemployment: both put downward pressure on inflation. What is more, Mr Bernanke and his colleagues reckon today’s low fed funds rate is merely offsetting tighter financial conditions from the credit crunch.
The hawks, by contrast, think that unemployment and other measures of “economic slack” have limited bearing on the transmission of monetary policy. Fed actions affect inflation primarily by altering inflation expectations. They worry that a low funds rate in itself threatens to lift inflation, and rising unemployment and the credit crunch will do little to contain it.
The divide inside today’s FOMC recalls the “freshwater-saltwater” split in macroeconomics in the 1970s and 1980s, when inland scholars such as those at the University of Minnesota challenged the Phillips-curve advocates at coastal universities like the Massachusetts Institute of Technology over their sympathy for activist policymaking. Appropriately, the latest challenge originated with research at the Minneapolis Fed earlier this decade that found no relationship between unemployment and inflation. The most outspoken hawk today is Jeffrey Lacker, a University of Wisconsin graduate who now heads the Richmond Fed. He dissented four times in 2006 and in June criticised the Fed’s expansion of lending to banks as risking both moral hazard and the Fed’s independence.
Although some hawks rile their colleagues with the rigidity of their views, they are not a threat to Mr Bernanke’s leadership. For one thing, his fellow governors in Washington, DC, are united behind him. For another, the hawks are grateful for being encouraged to air their disagreements. The hawkish chatter may at times muddle the Fed’s message, but it probably means the FOMC is working as it should. |
|